![]() |
Home | Search | Browse | About IPO | Staff | Links |
STATE JOBS:
ECONOMIC BOON OR BUST? Despite the movement to downsize government at all levels, there are many hard-pressed communities that look to public sector jobs as their economic salvation. In recent years, the lure of new jobs has pitted dozens of towns and cities against each other in a costly competition to host new state prisons. But is there a payoff? On the cost-benefit ledger, what are the gains or drawbacks of government jobs? Economics writer David Moberg explores the payoffs and problems of looking to government as a source of economic well-being. by David Moberg Photographs by Judy Spencer
In the late '70s, with local farms and factories humming, the citizens of Galesburg were largely hostile to the idea of the state Department of Corrections building a prison in their hometown. Most people seemed to think it could be both dangerous and a blight on this western Illinois community of 35,000.
Then, in 1981, Outboard Marine Corp. shut down a local factory employing more than 800 workers, and a few months later Gov. James R. Thompson announced the closing of Galesburg Mental Health Center, with the loss of 950 more jobs. The next year, when Thompson announced a major prison construction program, Galesburg had changed. It was one of the more than three dozen communities expressing interest in a prison. Many
14 * February 1996 Illinois Issues
Illinois Issues February 1996 * 15
remaining skeptics in town were quieted when corrections officials took a
busload of them on a tour contrasting
Hillsboro, where a new prison sustained a lively retail industry in the
center of town, and nearby Litchfield,
where a third of local stores were
closed. Galesburg was one of three
towns to win its bid, and the Henry
Hill Correctional Center opened in
1987, employing about 400 people.
"When you're looking at a 22 percent unemployment rate, there are
some things you do that you wouldn't
do otherwise," Galesburg Mayor Fred
Kimble observes matter-of-factly. "We
needed those 400 jobs." Despite a few
setbacks along the way, Galesburg has
recovered much lost ground since then.
With some state "Build Illinois" aid,
the mental health center land now
dubbed Hawthorne Center has
become home to a variety of not-for-profit and for-profit enterprises, state
and local government agencies, and a
successful business incubator run by
the local community college. All told,
Kimble estimates, the new enterprises
now provide nearly as many jobs as the
mental health center did. Other key
businesses in town also have gained
strength, and a new firm now occupies
the old Outboard Marine building.
So when the federal government was
looking for a central Illinois site for a
new prison a few years ago, community leaders were surprised to find substantial public opposition. The leaders
had reasoned that if one prison is
good, two would be better. But, Kimble recalls, the average citizen thought,
"One is enough. Times are better, and
we're susceptible to the same 'not in
my backyard' fears as others." Given a
choice of jobs, most people put prisons way down on their list.
Over the past 15 years, as Illinois
communities have been rocked by the
loss of nearly half a million manufacturing jobs and other economic
upheavals, many have like Galesburg
looked to the state to fill the void.
Hard times forced Galesburg and smaller towns to seek prison jobs they once
might have spurned. Prisons were growing fast and had the advantage of flexibility in location, unlike agencies that
need to be near the people served (such
as Children and Family Services workers concentrated in metro Chicago).
There are clear economic benefits
from jobs in these and other state
agencies that are dramatically evident
in small communities. Yet the experience in Galesburg suggests that most
people would quite justifiably prefer to
build their local economies on such
options as private factories and white-collar offices or public universities and
research centers. However, in recent
years the state has been more likely to
offer such towns corrections facilities.
"It's a sad commentary on the state
of Illinois that the overall economic
strategy has come down to building of
prisons or expansion of gambling,"
laments Democratic state Sen. Penny
Severns of Decatur.
Not-so-big government
Nobody can blame communities for
trying whatever they can to revive
hard-hit local economies, especially
when public sector jobs are often relatively well-paid and stable. And at
least some public jobs generate other
lasting benefits that spread through
the local economy.
Public sector paychecks once were
far from generous, but with the power
of their unions behind them, public
employees today often are as well or
better paid than comparable private
sector workers and have more security.
Prison security guards, for example,
make $26,000 a year or more and have
good benefits. Because these state jobs
are less dependent on the boom and
bust of the private economy, cities like
Galesburg seek public employers.
Kimble says, "They make a contribution to the economic base that helps
you resist fluctuations."
Also, with public sector jobs, government can target its investment to
some extent in places that the private
market has neglected, or favor local
suppliers to spur economic development (as Mayor Harold Washington
did in Chicago). Especially when they
efficiently provide useful services, public agencies are a positive economic
force, counterbalancing the regional
shifts and imbalances of the private
sector.
To the extent that public sector jobs
do offer economic benefits, Illinois
may be losing out compared to other
states. By almost any measure, Illinois
has a skimpy public sector. With about
168,600 employees out of a nonfarm
state work force of 5,604,200, Illinois
government employs a smaller percentage of its nonfarm work force
than any other state, according to
Bureau of Labor Statistics figures for
1995. In 1989, Illinois ranked 49th in
per capita expenditures for state wages
and 48th in the number of state
employees per 10,000 population.
Budgets reflect priorities and the
growth in state spending has not, in
recent years, come in areas that generate significant private economic activity or long-term economic benefits,
such as investments in education. Of
all budget categories, Medicaid, established in 1965, is among the fastest
growing, rising from 14 percent of the
state budget in 1975 to 26 percent in
1995. Human services dropped by
more than half from 1965 to 1985,
then crept up slightly to its current
share, 19 percent. Aid to Families with
Dependent Children, the main "welfare" program and the object of widespread political assault, has declined
the most of all major state programs,
from 14 percent of the budget in 1965
to only 6 percent in 1995. Universities,
with about 36,000 full-time and 20,000
part-time employees, account for the
largest bloc of state workers. Still, Illinois ranks near the bottom 47th among all the states in the percentage
of "gross state product" (total output
of goods and services) devoted to education. Over the past three decades
education's share of the state budget
dropped from 44 percent in 1965 to 34
percent in 1995.
Meanwhile, as both tougher sentencing laws and the war on drugs greatly
increased the numbers of prisoners,
the corrections budget, while still relatively small, has grown much faster
than any other category. It grew from 1
percent of spending in 1965 to 5.9 percent in 1995. Yet this only accounts for
money spent to run prisons, not the
cost of constructing new ones. Since
1973, the state has also appropriated
$1.2 trillion for building new prison
capacity, nearly one-fifth of total capi-
16 * February 1996 Illinois Issues
tal spending in Illinois. The spending
greatly accelerated after 1978; in the
five years from 1973 to 1977 corrections claimed only 3.5 percent of capital spending.
Some public investments do more
than others, providing not just immediate jobs but a basis for sustained
growth in productivity. The tragedy of
the prison boom is not simply that corrections facilities, which thrive on the
human misery of crime and punishment, are the fastest growing state
function. On top of that, prisons are a
weak tool for economic development.
They are less likely to foster long-term
economic growth or higher incomes
than public investments in education,
research or basic infrastructure, for
example. Unfortunately, with budgets
tight, rising prison costs compete with
other uses for state funds.
Ultimately, however, public sector
jobs must be judged by more than narrow economic standards, such as the
effects of payrolls, local business
growth or taxes on a single town like
Galesburg. A government enterprise
should first embody good public policy. That is, it should do such things as
educate children well, care humanely
for the disadvantaged or maintain
public order while protecting freedom.
Yet even if social values come first,
government has an interest in its operations being both efficient and contributing to regional economic vitality.
Economic judgments on public enterprises should be made on benefits and
costs in the broadest sense, looking at
direct and indirect effects and alternative policies.
A high price
There are, of course, potential drawbacks to an economic reliance on public sector jobs. Politics and policies do
change, even if not as predictably as
business cycles. What once seemed like
rock-solid jobs can suddenly wither
away, as a military base or mental
hospital closes. Dependence on public
jobs thus means dependence on political and social trends. And simply
because a community has an opportunity to attract a public facility, like a
prison or military base, does not mean
that those jobs are the best option for
the local economy. Finally, in their
desperate competition for jobs,
whether public or private, communities often pay too high a price.
Because of its rapid growth, the corrections department has most strikingly posed the question of the relative
economic benefits of public employment in recent years. In the early '80s,
when the prison building boom accelerated, the Department of Corrections
opened the process of prison site selection to intense bidding, taking into
account appropriateness of the site for
the state, local community support,
and, last, economic need. There were
many communities in need.
"Sometimes it gets ludicrous," says
Nic Howell, spokesman for the
Department of Corrections. "One
Illinois Issues February 1996 * 17
Consider the battle for "Supermax,"
a new maximum security prison now
under construction.
Jerry L. Reppert publishes the newspaper in Anna, a town of 5,000 in deep
southern Illinois that had lost 700 jobs
from two factory closings in 1992. "I
decided to go to Springfield to see what
new might be coming up that we might
go after," he says. "I had no intention of
looking for a prison." But after bouncing from one agency to another with no
luck, he ended up at the Department of
Corrections. He then returned home to
form the Southernmost Illinois Prison
Committee to compete for Supermax.
"My thinking was strictly jobs," he says.
"We needed jobs and the payroll that
came with them."
Besides mounting a petition drive in
support of the prison, the surrounding
communities offered to buy the property and give it to the state, extend utilities to the site at no cost and offer free
water and sewer service for two years.
To raise money for the land, the committee asked local people to buy "honorary ownership" at $100 a share. This
voluntary contribution brought about
$100,000 toward the $1.4 million cost
to the village of Tamms, population
700, where the prison was located.
Last fall, Pinckneyville offered a
package of incentives worth $8 million
to win a new medium security prison.
The town, hard hit by coal mine closings that cost more than 1,500 jobs,
wanted to expand its manufacturing
base and opened a new industrial
park. By winning the prison, argues
Tom Denton, who doubles as police
chief and economic development coordinator, the town could justify extending utilities to develop the new industrial site near the proposed prison.
"There's a considerable cost [for the
prison], but we needed to do the infrastructure anyway," he says. "We
wouldn't necessarily go into an $8 million investment for a private corporation that could leave, but prisons are a
stable building block."
Now, Denton says, the once-shuttered stores in town are filled, and new
businesses are making inquiries. "I
think they see $20 million [the annual
payroll] reverberating through the
economy as a plus," he says. "The fact
that we were most competitive in the
eyes of the state also brought us a lot
of attention."
Most of the new prison sites report
prison-stimulated boomlets in retail
sales, mainly from the prison employee
payroll but also for some local purchases of goods and services for the
prison. Robinson, a southeastern Illinois town of 7,500 where unemployment hit 26 percent in 1986, was so
pleased with the minimum security
prison that opened in 1990 that it
applied again last year for the prison
that ultimately went to Pinckneyville.
"We look at the prison as one of our
development partners, an industry in
town, and, like it or not, a growth
industry," says Peggy Keen, executive
director of the area Chamber of Commerce. After the prison opened,
though not entirely because of it, sales
tax revenue increased by 20 percent,
unemployment dropped 2.5 points to
7.7 percent, and both the industrial
and commercial tax base have jumped
nearly 40 percent.
The prison sweepstakes
No wonder prisons have become
popular. But that popularity may distort the selection of sites, skewing the
process to favor small, hard-pressed
downstate towns over midsized cities
that are equally in need of jobs but
where opposition tends to be more
vocal. The process is not immune to
political manipulation, and critics
have complained that Republican governors have chosen sites that would be
beneficial to GOP legislative interests.
Moreover, the state's siting process
encourages communities to bid against
each other with incentive packages
that are costly to already depressed
towns and villages and at odds with
Edgar Administration policy that, at
least ostensibly, eschews use of incentives to lure new jobs to an area.
Most communities believe that the
long-term benefits will exceed the cost.
They may be right, though typically
they vastly exaggerate the indirect
effects of the prison in their projections.
Boosters often claim that the prison
payroll will ripple through the local
economy, generating five or six times
the number of prison jobs in other local
businesses, from hardware stores to
fast-food outlets. But economist Joseph
Persky of the University of Illinois at
Chicago argues that, on average, the
correct "multiplier" of economic
impact for public facilities is only 1.6 to
two times as many jobs in peripheral
firms as in the core business. The multiplier calculation for private companies
tends to run higher as many as three
spinoff jobs for each job an auto plant,
for example, brings to town.
Even if the community recovers its
incentive package, is it proper for the
state to encourage such subsidization?
After all, the bidders are virtually all
among the most economically distressed communities in the state. If it
were not for the incentives, revenue for
building and maintaining the new prisons would come out of taxes, which are
slightly progressive, falling a bit more
on the wealthy Chicago suburbs.
Defenders of the process say that the
state is simply getting the best deal it
can for itself. "Being a taxpayer, it
doesn't bother me at all," says corrections spokesman Howell. "The kind of
incentives these communities offer is
the same they'd offer any big business."
But the state is supposed to operate
on more socially responsible principles
than a business. Besides, officially, the
state of Illinois now deplores the way
businesses try to get tax breaks to
locate factories or offices. Though
Thompson aggressively bid for new
factories with government subsidies,
Gov. Jim Edgar has downplayed the
incentive bidding game.
18 * February 1996 Illinois Issues
Nevertheless, critics maintain, the
state has inappropriately encouraged a
similar contest among communities
for prisons. "If the state of Illinois had
made the decision that they're not
going to ante up huge quantities of
money to attract businesses," Galesburg Mayor Kimble says, "I'd hope
they'd be consistent and not require
such sums for communities within the
state." For her part Sen. Severns
argues, "Instead of putting communities into a bidding war, I believe decisions should be made on where can it
do the most good, provide the most
hope, have the most economic impact
and serve the economic interest of
most families."
J. Fred Giertz, professor of economics at the University of Illinois at
Urbana-Champaign, does not
adamantly oppose community incentives but contends that "the state
shouldn't go around squeezing areas
and do like firms in pitting one area
against another. It's strange. State government doesn't like that game when
it's played by firms, but to a certain
extent, they're doing the same."
Balancing the ledger
Despite obvious benefits to some
small communities, a more comprehensive balance sheet calls into question the value of prisons as an economic development tool. Social policy
choices carry economic consequences.
It is thus misleading to judge even the
economic impact of an institution like
a prison too narrowly. With certain
crimes and criminals, incarceration is
the costliest alternative, robbing scarce
state dollars from more productive
economic enterprises to build prisons.
The first question that needs to be
asked is: Do we really need them? In
the long run, it makes little economic
sense to provide unneeded services. No
one would argue against locking away
criminals who are a clear danger to
society. Clearly, removing destructive
individuals from society brings economic as well as social rewards. But
many critics contend that tougher sentencing laws have less to do with protecting society than with vengeance
and political grandstanding. Also,
locking up nonviolent offenders with
hardened criminals may end up having
the negative economic effect of creating "schools for crime."
Similarly, a growing number of critics question the use of the criminal
justice system and prisons to deal with
the vast majority of drug problems.
They argue that drugs are a public
health problem, best addressed
through education and treatment and
an overall strategy of "minimization
of harm" rather than punishment.
Within that broad strategy, employed
by most Western European countries,
Illinois Issues February 1996 * 19
These drug policy revisionists, ranging from conservative economist Milton Friedman to Baltimore Mayor
Kurt Schmoke, argue that the vast
majority of drug-related criminal
offenses result primarily not from the
"high" that comes from drugs but
from their illegality. Criminalizing
drugs pushes up prices, turning drug
abusers to crime to support their habit,
and stimulates the deadly war among
participants in the drug trade.
Few approaches are economically
costlier than what we are now doing,
critics say. For example, David Olson
and Roger Przybylski of the Illinois
Criminal Justice Authority found that
arrest, trial and incarceration for the
average drug offender cost $36,452.
Probation for the same offender costs
$6,067. The cost of drug treatment ranging from roughly $4,000 for an
intensive outpatient program to
$15,000 for inpatient treatment is
far less than prison. It also is more
effective. (Even if abusers in drug
treatment programs eventually return
to drug use, there is strong evidence
that their criminal behavior greatly
declines during treatment, more than
repaying the cost.) A recent Rand Corporation study found that every dollar
spent in drug treatment yielded $7 in
such benefits to society as reduced
crime, reduced drug consumption and
lower health costs.
"It is not just criminals who are
paying an exaggerated price for America's addiction to incarceration," the
conservative British weekly, The Economist, argued last December. "The
criminal minority, in effect, consumes
an increasingly disproportionate share
of the public purse. State spending on
prisons has increased more than sixfold in real terms since 1979, using
money that could have been spent on
education, parks and hospitals. Getting tough on crime is punishing not
just the bad guys, but law-abiding citizens as well."
Thus, in weighing the benefits of
new jobs in Pinckneyville versus the
total cost to the state of an expensive,
ineffective war on drugs, both the economic development and public policy
scales tip toward new approaches to
drug problems, not more prisons.
Inevitably, using such a comprehensive
balance sheet involves the complex
task of assessing the economic costs
and benefits of social policy, not simply jobs generated by building and
operating a new prison. The economic
value of a new prison thus looks quite
different when viewed from Pinckneyville or when viewed in terms of
the interests of the state as a whole.
The lure of prisons as a solution to
local woes may also divert local communities from pursuing more productive economic strategies. Savanna lost
its bid last year to locate a prison on a
nearby army depot that is shutting
down over the next couple of years.
Though it is now starting an economic
development effort, the town is still
keeping an eye on the prison sweepstakes. "We're not going to give up,"
says Mayor Eugene Flack. "They do
one of these penitentiaries about every
year. We hope one of these years we'll
get one up here."
Despite their appeal, prisons aren't
even the best development option for
many communities. The problem is, as
Jerry Reppert found when he went on
his search to Springfield, sometimes
they're the only option available. "Prisons aren't the ideal economic development facility, but they're better than
nothing," observes Giertz. "They just
redistribute [money] from one area of
the state to another. It doesn't make
the state any better economically,
except to reduce crime."
Finding alternatives
In weighing the economic benefits of
prisons, it is also worth asking what
the alternatives might be. Most of
them, unfortunately, do not provide
the quick fix of a prison, but most of
them do provide more long-term benefits. Galesburg discovered some of the
better alternatives: encouraging
growth of existing enterprises, incubators for new business, creative reuse of
facilities, and development of local
education and training. Instead of
more prisons, Rep. Mike Boland, an
East Moline Democrat, would rather
see a branch of a state university in his
Quad Cities region, and a new highway linking the area to St. Louis. The
state, which is now thinking of
expanding the use of convict labor for
recycling, could instead invest in recycling and related manufacturing enterprises that could create new civilian
jobs in many depressed areas through
both nonprofit and for-profit enterprises.
The state could also help reduce the
great inequities of spending on education, which afflict many small downstate communities as well as poor
parts of the Chicago metropolitan
region. The Corporation for Enterprise Development, a Washington-based think tank focused on economic
development, last year cited Illinois'
tax and fiscal system as among the
nation's 10 worst in terms of equalizing local fiscal capacity and as a drag
on the state's economic performance.
Education pays off handsomely for
both individuals and society. Economists consider the "social rate of
return" on an investment as the
increase in personal income compared
to the investment made. Though some
economists might stress the economic
benefits of social order resulting from
imprisonment of criminals, Walter
McMahon, a professor of economics
at the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, sees the rate of return on
prisons as negative (since they function as schools for crime). On the other hand, he argues that the rate of
return on education is about 12 percent per year, only a bit less than the
average return on investment in manu-
20 * February 1996 Illinois Issues
facturing plants and equipment. In
addition, education provides substantial "nonmonetary returns, including
reduction of poverty, reduction of
inequality, democratization and lower
crime rates," he argues.
Even with much more money for
schools, however, there would still be
crime and the need for prisons, though
probably fewer than today. If prisons
must be built, they can boost local
economies, but the system would work
better if there were fewer political considerations and no incentive game.
Some gain, some lose
If some communities are keenly
anticipating what new state facilities
might open, others are equally worried
that they might lose what they have.
Although Illinois has closed only one
prison in its history, government has
shut down many other institutions
that were long considered economic
anchors of their communities. But
critics, including the public employee
union, argue that the state does not
weigh local job needs as seriously
when closing facilities like mental
health centers as it does in touting the
opening of new prisons.
"It drives me crazy that people make
a big deal over a business closing with
85 jobs, and we close a mental health
facility with 300 jobs, and nobody
thinks it has an economic development
impact," argues Roberta Lynch,
deputy director of Council 31 of the
American Federation of State, County
and Municipal Employees
(AFSCME), which represents more
than 40,000 state workers.
While all shutdowns take a toll,
some have less impact because there
are more opportunities for conversion
of facilities or alternative employment
for workers. For example, in recent
years the federal government has
closed many military bases and facilities, including Glenview Naval Air Station, Great Lakes Naval Training Center, Chanute Air Force Base in
Rantoul, the Joliet Arsenal and the
Savanna Army Depot. The main concern with the two north suburban sites
was which of many competing private
and public uses would be adopted.
But not every base closing is so
benign. Following the 1993 decommissioning of Chanute, the Bureau of
Economic and Business Research at
the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign tracked the local economy. Though they find local optimism,
especially with the prospect of a new
Defense Department accounting center at the base, the 1995 report said the
local economy is not "particularly
strong." Compared to some forecasts,
"the impact was minor," argues Bank
of Rantoul President Tom Bryan, and
parts of the base have been developed
for private businesses and housing.
Other than federal bases, community concern about closing of public
facilities has focused on state mental
hospitals and residential facilities for
the developmentally disabled. There
has been a long-term decline in population and the number of centers as
philosophies about caring for both
groups has changed dramatically.
From a high of 56,587 in 1940, the
combined population of these facilities dropped to 17,344 in 1970, 9,875
in 1980 and 6,245 currently. Since 1977
the Department of Mental Health and
Developmental Disabilities has closed
nine facilities with more than 2,000
beds, shifting many patients or residents to nonprofit and for-profit community institutions (which now care
for about 3,259 mental patients and
6,105 developmentally disabled people
at state expense).
The change reflected a new
approach to treatment for the mentally
ill, including greater use of drugs,
attempts to integrate the mentally ill
into community life and the recognition of civil rights for the mentally ill.
It also reflected the effort supported
by parents and most educators to
teach developmentally disabled children in the schools, rather than simply
warehouse them. Especially with the
mentally ill, the state also saw deinstitutionalization as a way to save money.
But critics argue that many of the
mentally ill have not received adequate
treatment on release and have not
fared well, often ending up homeless
or "relabeled" and reinstitutionalized
in prisons. In several cases, prisons
have been built on or near the sites of
former mental hospitals, easing the
pain of closings but unintentionally
reflecting a shift in types of incarceration for some individuals. Some former state workers find jobs in the privatized community programs but
typically at much lower pay.
Last year Edgar announced closings
of both the Meyer Mental Health
Center in Decatur and the Kiley
Developmental Center in Waukegan.
In both cases, the state planned to disperse residents to community institutions. AFSCME fought both closings,
stressing the economic loss and the
inadequacy of the community alternatives. With strong backing from parents, many of whom praised the Kiley
staff and had experienced serious
problems with private facilities, the
coalition against the Kiley closing won
a reprieve for at least five years.
UlC's Persky concluded that in
addition to 669 jobs directly lost to
Kiley layoffs, the four-county area
would lose another 252 jobs and the
metropolitan area another 571 jobs,
with a loss of $65 million in income to
the area through the year 2000.
Though the state projected saving $4
million a year with the closing, Persky's study concluded that the state
would lose nearly $5 million in income
tax revenue through 2000, plus losses
of sales and property taxes for different levels of government.
Illinois Issues February 1996 * 21
Two-edged sword
The transformation of the Department of Mental Health and Developmental Disabilities is a case study in
the difference that public employment
can mean for moderately skilled workers. At the publicly operated facilities,
the average caregiver, like a certified
nurse's assistant, makes about $24,000
a year, but in private agencies the starting wage in 1992 was only $9,256 a
year for the same work, well below the
poverty level. Few of the private sector
workers have pensions or health insurance, unlike the public employees.
Still, reliance on private sector agencies has become an important means of
providing public services. The state
spends more than $550 million a year
from the departments of Public Aid
and Mental Health at more than 500
private agencies, supporting a "shadow
public sector," according to AFSCME
calculations. Counting all social service
agencies with private subcontractors
supported by the public purse, this
"shadow sector" may total 30,000 to
40,000 workers, based on various public employee union estimates.
The government and thus taxpayers may save money by privatizing
this social service work. But as Geoffrey Hewings, director of the Regional
Economics Applications Laboratory at
the University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign, notes, "If you unburden
one part of the state and privatize it,
and the private providers do the work
with uninsured workers, then we have
to look at the cost to the state of providing medical care. We may save one
dollar with one hand and spend 95
cents with the other."
Also, the savings to the state may
not be as great as the loss to workers.
According to AFSCME calculations,
the cost per bed per day at the one privately managed veterans home is
about 10 percent less than the cost at
the three state-run homes, but typical
wages are often 40 percent less.
AFSCME recently won an election to
represent the privatized home workers
and hopes to raise their wages.
From the standpoint of the economy as a whole, privatization often
brings no real gain. It usually entails
wage cuts, and that doesn't make society more productive, says economist
Persky. Those cuts simply transfer
income from workers to someone else
the private employer, managers or
taxpayers, for example. But to the
extent that the tax system is progressive, or low wages are an alternative to
raising needed revenues by making the
system more progressive, then the
main taxpayer beneficiaries are those
with the highest incomes.
"Unless someone can show me there
are real efficiency gains, that is, more
output per unit of physical input, I'm
real dubious about the value of privatization," Persky says. For example,
when the university privatized its food
service, which retained the same people
but cut wages, "that's not a gain in efficiency," he says. "You would hope the
public sector wouldn't get caught in
this race to the bottom."
Slashing wages does make workers
poorer at a time when one of the
biggest economic problems of the
country and state is the stagnation of
wages. Wage cuts hurt the rest of the
economy (since workers buy less),
damages the fabric of society (by
increasing inequality and social tensions), and may contribute to future
social problems, which will cost the
state more later.
AFSCME, traditionally a public
employee union, has launched an effort
in recent years to organize the shadow
sector workers. So far it has won elections to represent workers in several
locations, though some private employers are resisting signing a contract.
That's another consequence of privatization: It is harder for workers to
unionize in the private sector and gain
a collective voice at work. The Service
Employees International Union has
also organized an estimated 10,000
home care workers, who work for private employers reimbursed by the state,
and has forced the state to raise their
abysmally low compensation.
Several unions are also collaborating
with ACORN, the community group,
to pass a "living wage" ordinance in
Chicago, similar to an ordinance
passed in 1994 in Baltimore and now
being pushed in several cities around
the country. It would require any contractor with the city, or beneficiary of
city subsidies such as tax breaks, to
pay a wage sufficient to bring a family
of four above the federal poverty line,
or about $7.60 an hour. There may be
a push for a similar "living wage" law
at the state level.
Obviously the level of wages or benefits should not be the only consideration in decisions about privatization. If
the private sector truly is more efficient producing more with less or provides better products or services,
then there could still be a case for privatization. But privatization typically
means less public accountability or
openness to scrutiny by the press or
government.
In many cases, it also brings shoddier products or services, not improvements. For example, according to a
1992 study by David Braddock and
Dale Mitchell of the University of Illinois at Chicago, 87.2 percent of the
staff on average changes each year at
privately run agencies for the develop-
22 * February 1996 Illinois Issues
mentally disabled compared to a
turnover rate of 13.7 percent at state
facilities. In addition, private agencies
provide only 56 hours of on-the-job
training compared to 394 hours at
state-run institutions. The result is frequently poor quality care, even
appalling conditions, according to the
Department of Mental Health inspector general. But those failings are hidden from the public eye, unlike the
more regularly reported shortcomings
of state institutions.
Public agencies certainly deserve
continued scrutiny to improve efficiency and quality and to guarantee that
their services are indeed useful. But it
is important to remember that state or
other government jobs can be building
blocks of economic prosperity for
both local communities and the state.
From an economic point of view, education, research and creation of new
infrastructure are among the most
productive traditional public activities.
Yet even though it makes sense to gain
the greatest possible economic development advantage from government
enterprises, it is a mistake to view government as just another business or to
judge every policy or agency in narrow
economic terms.
In any ease, the economic benefits
must be totaled on a comprehensive
balance sheet. Such accounting can
reveal that what looks like a promising
job creation tool, such as building a
new prison, can really be an economic
deadweight compared to alternatives
such as drug treatment or alternative
sentencing for nonviolent offenses.
Privatization, in particular, deserves
close scrutiny to see if it brings both
true efficiency and higher quality.
Turning work over to the private sector is no panacea, though it may be
justified under certain circumstances,
such as some of the community mental health programs. Still, Illinois certainly does not suffer from a bloated
public sector. When privatization
means simply hardship for workers, a
diminished stimulus to the economy
and less accountability to the community, then it's a bad deal. If the private
sector is going to deliver public goods,
then it must be superior in all regards
to a public agency, not just cheaper in
the short run.
In the long run, economic vitality
will come, as it has to some extent in
Galesburg, from a judicious mix of
public and private initiatives. In an era
when all government is portrayed as a
drain on the economy, it is important
to remember that the right kind of
public initiatives even expanded
beyond what they are now can be
foundations for a healthier private
economy as well as being in themselves
important sources of badly needed
jobs. *
David Moberg, senior editor at In These
Times, writes widely on economic issues.
His articles have appeared in The New
Republic, The New York Times and the
Chicago Tribune. His previous article for Illinois Issues examined the labor movement.
Illinois Issues February 1996 * 23 |
Sam S. Manivong, Illinois Periodicals Online Coordinator |